Quote on Openness in Government

The Bovine Spongiform Encephalopathy (BSE) Inquiry, United Kingdom

“Our experience over this lengthy Inquiry has led us to the firm conclusion that a policy of openness is the correct approach. When responding to public or media demand for advice, the government must resist the temptation of attempting to appear to have all the answers in a situation of uncertainty. We believe that food scares and vaccine scares thrive on the belief that the Government is withholding information. If doubts are openly expressed and publicly explored, the public are capable of responding rationally and are more likely to accept reassurance and advice

if and when it comes.”

Quoted on page 40 of the WHO World Health Report 2002. (Here)

This seems to be also pertinent to the Climate Science in general and the UNIPCC in particular.

The BSE Inquiry Report details

http://www.cabdirect.org/abstracts/20002219667.html;jsessionid=42B120D8A52B9E491149695EB22E4EEB

Abstract

The inquiry was set up in 1997 to: establish and review the history and emergence and identification of BSE and variant CJD in the UK and of the action taken in response to it up to March 1996; to reach conclusions on the adequacy of that response; and to report the findings to relevant ministries. The resulting report documents in detail the development of two new diseases, one of cattle that devastated the British cattle industry (more than 170000 animals affected) and another that has caused the deaths of more than 80 people so far. The report identifies several shortcomings in delayed responses and lack of rigour in implementing measures. Poor coordination between health and agricultural departments and bureaucracy impeded prompt responses. The cause of the epidemic was identified as the inclusion of meat and bone meal in ruminant feed. Despite the banning of specified bovine offals in ruminant feed in 1990, cattle born after this date still contracted the disease, probably through cross contamination of feed with feed destined for non-ruminants. The report makes compelling reading for all those who have followed the epidemic. It is available from The Stationary Office (http://www.thestationeryoffice.com/bse/) in print (#325 for the complete boxed set of 16 volumes [ISBN 0105569860]; or #29.50 for Volume 1: Findings and Conclusions [contains a CD-ROM of the full text of the report; ISBN 0105569704]), on CD-ROM (#235 which includes the full text of the report on Disc 1. Discs 2-12 include all the witness statements, transcripts, SEAC and ACAF documents and other supporting documents; ISBN: 0105569879), or can be freely accessed on the Internet.

Climate Change in Perspective – Part 2 of 4 – The Mitigation Curve

 

The previous posting developed a simple graph showing the consensus case for climate change mitigation. This posting looks at the policy arguments, suggesting a huge gap between what is believed to be theoretically possible and what may be realistically achieved. The conclusion is stark. Mitigation policy optimization requires a political process that cannot deliver a result that will leave the world better for future generations.

The Mitigation Cost Curve

The previous posting presented in graphical form the consensus argument (UN IPCC & Stern) for stabilizing CO2 at around double the pre-industrial level, along with stabilizing other greenhouse gas emissions. That is that the costs of constraining the growth in levels of CO2 – are much less than the costs of allowing greenhouse gases temperature rises to go unchecked. Mitigation is essentially a cost minimization strategy with the Stern Review claims the benefits outweigh the costs 5 to 20 times. To put this into context, the Review states that the expected mean costs of mitigation will be annually 1% of annual global product (GWP). The costs of the actual climate change impact could be 5% of GDP or more.

The Prudent approach from this graph is to aim for point P. That is not the absolute minimum costs, but still much lower cost than the likely costs of doing nothing.

What is important to note is that the policy is not to reduce CO2 levels from the current levels of around 380ppm, but to stabilize the growth in emissions. This growth in emissions will come from the emerging economies, in particular from China where emissions per capita have recently been growing by 12% a year. The OECD countries have had largely static emissions per capita, and the population is very slow growing as well.

To turn theory into successful stabilization of CO2 at 550 to 600ppm, requires quite a extended process. I have attempted to break down this process into a flow chart showing the major steps. Next to each step is an arrow suggesting the direction the curve will move if the process is less than perfect.

 

The graph below shows the impact on the mitigation curve of a movement in the arrows.

A movement to the right will shift the curve from M to M’. This is when the marginal costs increase. A movement upwards will shift the curve from M to M”. This is when costs are incurred that totally ineffective in influencing on CO2 levels. Finally there are policy shifts upwards and to the right, from M to M”’, which is a combination of higher marginal costs and ineffective elements.

Looking at the issues in turn.

Economic Theory

I will assume that the shape and position of the curve is correct. That is, there is a set of policies or actions in the real world that if applied will achieve the outcomes desired. However, these have to be discovered. Some low-cost constraints will be quite easy to discover. Others might be more difficult, relying on estimates from self-interested parties. The optimal policies will not be given for long periods, but could change over time with relative costs and technological advances. For instance, a technological breakthrough enabling much cheaper and compact batteries could transform the viability of electric cars. Therefore the switch from gasoline and diesel could be achieved with little or no subsidies.

A second assumption is that although the right economic policies will cost money, the optimal policies will have absolutely no impact on economic growth. This is a crucial assumption of the Stern Review. The policy costs will amount to around 1% of GDP at the end of the century, against costs of around 5% of GDP of climate change impacts if nothing is done. However, if growth rates are reduced by just 0.1% then in ninety years output will be over 9% lower. It is quite conceivable that a drastic change in climate policy would reduce China’s growth rate by 0.5%. By 2100 this would mean output was a full 35% lower than without the policy change. If growth by then has slowed to 3% per annum, living standards would lag 25 years, or a generation, behind where they would have been. Even if the 0.5% growth reduction is for just the first 40 years, output is still 17% lower. There may be a preference of trading a 9% lower living standards with certainty, to possible suffering from the harmful and random effects that will costAny policy that fails to recognize this

Equity

A simplistic analysis would take into account the actual costs. The cheapest ways to constrain growth in emissions is to impose a uniform policy globally. A country like Ethiopia, for instance, has nominal GDP per capita of less than 1% of the OECD average ($330 against $39473) according to World Bank Data. The real impact of a uniform carbon tax will be disproportionately felt by the poorest. The UNIPCC and Stern recognize this, but have not made an adequate provision allowance. The proposals are for the rich countries bear the overwhelming burden of the constraint in emissions and for monetary transfers to enable the poorest to grow economically without increasing their CO2 emissions. Stern recommends that the rich countries reduce their emissions by 80% per capita by 2050. However, this split will not be totally equitable. Within countries there are large inequalities in income and wealth. For instance, the richest 10% in Brazil have far better life styles than the poorest 10% in the United States. Any split between countries will leave many of the rich and powerful untouched by the policies, whilst leaving the poor in the OECD countries worse off.

Policy Identification

There are a number of possible tools to achieve a cost effective containment of CO2 growth. These include Cap and Trade; Carbon Taxes; encouraging technological development; carbon sequestration; building (or regulating the building of) new carbon-neutral power stations; and promoting energy saving through subsidies and regulation. Minimizing the costs and maximising the effectiveness of this containment requires optimizing these alternatives in terms of extent, combination and timeliness. As we do not know when to use each of these in terms of time and place, there needs to be learning through experience. When policies or initiatives are not producing results, there needs to be quick and decisive actions in constraining, changing or abandonment. Yet these decisive decisions need to be taken in the context of often only vaguely perceiving, even retrospectively, whether we are taking the best course of actions. Are we pursuing the right sort of alternative power supply? Is funding for our favoured form of future technology the correct one? If that technological preference is broadly the best are we favouring the best approach, or disregarding a far more efficient alternative? Are we applying Cap and Trade too far, or is the design of the policy inappropriate to achieve optimal result? Are any carbon taxes delivering reductions in CO2 with our cost constraints?

If we fail to optimize then policies like Cap and Trade will generate marginal costs much higher than planned. The curve shifts to the right. If the research for new low-cost carbon neutral energy consumption fails, then the curve shifts upward as we waste money. So overall, sub-optimal policy choice will shift the curve upwards and to the right.

International Negotiation

Climate change policies need to be spread broadly to be effective. If major countries are excluded, then the burden of constraint on the others will be that much greater. Yet mitigation policy is to inflict some costs now to avoid much greater costs in two, five or twenty generations down in the future. To get

  • Overstate the urgency and the extent of the problem.
  • Understate or fudge the immediate cost implications.
  • Alienate any who raise the slightest question about the efficacy of such agreements. There are plenty of NGOs to do this.
  • Understate the alternatives.
  • Provide a world stage for the leaders, including those would normally be ostracized. (Such as here and here).
  • Leave aside the implementation problems.

 

International Polices & Targets

The fudging is likely to affect the final policy. Nation states do not accept strict targets within cost constraint, with punishments meted out to those that fail. They will not relinquish part of their sovereignty and possibly their economic growth easily. But the poorer ones, with promises of cash to help them out, will be enthusiastic. Therefore any final agreement will load costs on those keenest on the policy, and plenty of loop-holes to allow those with other priorities, or those with a weak political grasp on power, to fudge. This does not have to be a permanent fudge

National Policies

There will be a number of different approaches. Cutting or CO2 levels or constraining the growth requires long-term policies, with short-term plaudits. In Britain’s case the implementation CO2 reduction target of 80% gained much praise in the international community. But the costs are mostly left to successor governments. The favoured form of green energy is easy to promote, but the rising energy costs and the prospect of future energy blackouts on windless and frost winter nights will be blamed on later governments.

In the short-term there may be some job benefits and subsidies. Promoting Cap and Trade will create jobs for those administering the scheme and large profits for those who can easily reduce their emissions and sell on the carbon credits. There are also jobs to be had in climate research and the development of new technologies.

There is also political benefit to be had from providing a reason to raise taxes. In Britain the green taxes have mostly been loaded onto the motorist. Yet such a policy is likely to have very little marginal impact on CO2 emissions for precisely them same reason that it is a very good way of raising extra tax revenue – demand is very inelastic with respect to price. It is only with viable and cost-effective substitutes (electric to replace the internal combustion engine) that we will see a switch.

The nature of deriving and maintaining political census will be to have little project management from the top down. Therefore, there will be initiatives that were sub-optimal to start with and less effective moving forward. There will be little focus on research, but plenty on public relations. Rather than maximizing effectiveness and minimizing costs, there will be other, self-justifying matrices developed. The biggest justification will be international obligations.

Policy Outcomes and Policy Feedbacks

There may be plenty of policy and much more rhetoric, but the policy outcomes are likely to be feeble at great cost. However, to obtain and maintain the optimal policies, there must be a feedback process. This feedback needs to influence every level, including the economic theory as shown below.

This needs to be a continual and dynamic process. For this to happen there needs to be objective and honest analysis of results to better refine and amend our view of the optimal policies at both national and international level. The size of the arrows indicates my personal assessment of the importance of each aspect. The biggest feedback is in the continuous altering of national policies, to bring into line with optimal policies. But there must be an ability to easily change course at all levels. This requires not just openness and flexibility, but surrender of policy in this area to an international body. But countries will not easily agree to shoulder more of the burden, or lose subsidies. They will not easily be told that they must change course. Vested interests in the environmental matters do not have a unique humility and objectivity that is absent in other groups. Neither will politicians easily admit that they have made errors of judgment, or that there are areas where they have neither the competency nor power to act upon.

Conclusion

The process of implementing an optimal policy, requires an openness and flexibility that does not exist. The whole policy process works against this. Politics is about negotiation and compromise between competing interests. It is about jostling for power, rewarding supporters and undermining the influence of opponents. It is also about other priorities as well, which in the short-term are more pressing. In the section on economic theory we I showed how a small reduction in economic growth can more than offset the worst consequences of the policy.

The problem now becomes two-fold.

  1. Guaranteeing how the revised optimal policy P”’ will be less costly than doing nothing and letting the total climate impact costs reach CCImax.
  2. Justifying to the developed nations why they should be significantly worse off than doing nothing.

In the next posting I will look at the validity of the estimation of the costs of climate change.

 

Climate Change Policy in Perspective – Part 1 of 4

Introduction

In the Climate Change policy there lacks a simple framework to assess the policy. There is a large consensus of scientists telling us that a large rise in global temperature will occur, and that the only policy in offer is to constrain the growth in greenhouse gas emissions globally. Presented below is a simple graphical model to encapsulate the central policy arguments of the UNIPCC and the 2006 Stern Review. That is, there are policies that can be implemented that though costly, will be an order of magnitude less than the disastrous consequences of letting global temperatures rise unchecked. These consequences will not only affect the human race and for the rest of the planet. Use of this model allows analysis of the relative importance of various issues in devising policy and implementing global policies needed to achieve the consensus objectives.

The starting point for the analysis is to assume that two propositions are correct. First, that if we do nothing in two centuries global average temperatures will be at 5-10oC warmer than at present. Second, that there exists in theory a set of policies that will comfortably constrain CO2 emissions to prevent the atmospheric CO2 levels going above 600ppm and thus preventing global temperatures rising more than 2oC above current levels. I also start from a moral basis for policy that few will disagree with. Political action should only be taken if there is a reasonable expectation that the resulting outcome be a better situation than if no action was taken at all. The treatment, if not a full cure, should at least be expected to leave the patient in a better condition than without treatment. This, I would claim, is an absolute minimum requirement for action, as it can still leave moral dilemmas. For instance, if the policies cause the deaths of a million people, but prevents a 10% chance of 11 million people dying, then it is justified on this rule.

There are four parts to this explanation, which I will divide into separate blog postings. Part one, below, develops a graph replicating the standard consensus argument of the overwhelming consensus case for action. Part two addresses the issues with policy, relating this through movements in the policy curve. Part three evaluates the impacts of that warming, showing how changing the analysis of risk and time can radically change our perception of the costs. Part four brings these together for an overall conclusion, with indications of areas for further research.

The basis of the model is that global warming will create costly consequences, both for the human race and for the rest of the planet. Proposals to resolve this we also be costly. It is therefore to economics that we must turn to understand the issue from the top-down.

Part One – The Consensus Argument for Mitigation in Graphical Form

The following aims to replicate the mainstream consensus case of catastrophic climate change and the mitigation policies deemed necessary to combat it.

The Costly Consequences of Global Warming

We are already seeing some of the minor consequences of increasing greenhouse gases through disrupted climate. But the scientists tell us this will be as nothing compared to what will happen if greenhouse gases continue to increase unchecked for the next century or more. The large increases in temperature – around 4oC to 7oC or higher – would cause massive disruption to the climate system. It is fair to say that as global temperatures increase, these costs would increase exponentially. These “costs” are in the broadest sense. They are not just the human costs of property damage, failed harvests, population migrations and land being submerged by rising seas. These include the damage to the eco-systems and species extinction. Graphically it would look something like this.

There is no scale on this graph. It cannot be predicted how far temperatures will increase if the growth in anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions are not curtailed, nor at what point the catastrophic consequences will set in. What is essential to recognize is that allowing temperatures to increase will be many times worse than stabilizing that increase at lower temperatures. Without a check, it is near certain that the planet’s temperatures will climb to the top end of the graph with the level of costs predicted.

The Costs of Mitigation

The solution to the problem of climate change is to remove the cause of that change. To remove anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions totally would be hugely costly. The economic wealth of the rich countries is based upon fossil fuel energy consumption. Stop the energy consumption and you not only stop economic growth, but potentially cause economic collapse. Instead, there must be a rapid but orderly switch in energy use to clean energy sources. This may actually spur economic output as the switch is made, but is more likely to be costly, but have at most a negligible but negative impact on economic growth. Similarly, in the emerging BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India & China) economies, satisfying their rapidly-rising energy demands from carbon-neutral sources need not constrain their economic growth. Indeed for China and India real living standard could rise more rapidly, as the cities suffer less from the choking effects of the pollution from burning fossil fuels. How will these costs map out? To stop climate change now and reverse the impacts would be hugely costly. Even to stabilize emissions at current levels globally would be hugely expensive. In particular with China and India increasing their emission levels rapidly, to stabilize globally would require huge cuts elsewhere. Far less costly would be to stabilize at some higher level than at present.

The shape of the cost of mitigation graph can be represented like this.

The costs of doing little are very small, whilst those of stopping global warming in its tracks, or even reversing the warming that has already occurred, are huge. We are able to choose the policy to pursue.

The Combined Costs of Climate Change and Mitigation

Climate change will incur costs of CCI. Combating climate change involves mitigation costs M. For any temperature that stabilization is reached, the total costs TC will be CCI+M.

The question as to which level of policy to pursue now becomes clearer. A highly aggressive policy could be just as damaging as doing nothing. However, we are left with a large middle ground. By stabilizing the temperature increase from pre-industrial levels at around 2-3oC is generally thought to be where this middle ground lies. However, as there is some uncertainty as to what average temperature the worst effects of climate change start to come into play, a prudent policy is to aim at stabilization at the lower end of the temperature range. Prudent policy is at around point P.

Climate Change in Perspective Part 2 – The Mitigation Curve

Climate Change Impacts – UNIPCC and the Skeptics

Climate feedbacks are crucial to climate change forecasts. As Richard Lindzen1 said in his congressional testimony last year

  1. A doubling of CO2, by itself, contributes only about 1C to greenhouse warming. All models project more warming, because, within models, there are positive feedbacks from water vapor and clouds, and these feedbacks are considered by the IPCC to be uncertain.
  2. If one assumes all warming over the past century is due to anthropogenic greenhouse forcing, then the derived sensitivity of the climate to a doubling of CO2 is less than 1C. The higher sensitivity of existing models is made consistent with observed warming by invoking unknown additional negative forcings from aerosols and solar variability as arbitrary adjustments.

As Roy Spencer has recently claimed2,

In fact, NO ONE HAS YET FOUND A WAY WITH OBSERVATIONAL DATA TO TEST CLIMATE MODEL SENSITIVITY. This means we have no idea which of the climate models projections are more likely to come true.

Warren Meyer3 comments that

70-80% or more of the warming in catastrophic warming forecasts comes from feedback, not CO2 acting.

The impact is worse than that. It is not predicted temperature rise that is important. It is the catastrophic consequences that follow. These rise exponentially with temperature, so without the feedbacks more than 95% of the catastrophe does not happen. This is illustrated by the Climate Impacts table on page 10 of the UNIPCC Summary for policy makers4, where most of the impacts dramatically – almost exponentially – increase with temperature.

To illustrate this simply, the consequences of global warming will create costs. The reduced water availability, or crop failures will lead to increased hunger and in the extreme lead to deaths. The costs could also include the loss of species, both plant and animal.

To illustrate this graphically, plotting temperature increase against climate change costs, gives a Climate Change Impact curve as illustrated below.


There is no scale. There is no firm forecast of how high temperatures could go. The Stern review (Page 12) even saw fit to include a study with an upper estimate of 17.1oC maximum increase, and the UNIPCC AR4 has outlier estimates of 10oC. Neither do we know the costs. However, without the feedbacks, there is a temperature increase of around 1oC and so no hardly any noticeable costs. It is the pink line CCIS (S for skeptic) below.


 

References

  1. Quoted by Warren Meyer at http://www.climate-skeptic.com/2010/11/lindzen-testimony.html.

  2. Roy Spencer on 28th January 2011 http://www.drroyspencer.com/2011/01/update-further-evidence-of-low-climate-sensitivity-from-nasas-aqua-satellite/.
  3. http://www.climate-skeptic.com/2011/01/my-favorite-topic-feedback.html
  4. UNIPCC Summary for Policy Makers (SPM) reached from http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/syr/en/spms1.html

Greg Craven’s Grid Extended

Greg Craven published a series of Youtube videos claiming to give a stark a simple choice for any non-scientist to rise above the “shouting match” a beliefs to reach a decision, with confidence as what to do about climate change. By understanding the flaws in his argument it is possible to develop a more sophisticated grid that enables us to make a more rounded assessment of the climate change problem.

Craven’s Grid

Greg Craven is a high school science teacher in Oregon, who has produced a series of Youtube videos (and later in a book), asking:-

“Which is the more acceptable risk?

  • Do nothing and accept the potential catastrophe of global warming?
  • Take action now, potentially harming the economy, but averting potential catastrophe?”

He puts this into a simple grid, with whether to take action along the horizontal axis and whether the global warming hypothesis is true or not on the vertical axis. Recognising that there are costs to combating climate change he allows for the worst case scenario. The cost will be global depression. However, this is as nothing compared with the worst case scenario the scientists are telling us will happen if we do nothing. The choice is stark. We do not know whether the global warming hypothesis is true or false – that is a shouting match that we will get no sense out of – but we should not take a chance, for our own sakes, the sake of the world’s poor and the sake of our children.

Craven’s Grid

Action?

Global Warming?

Lots Now

Little or None Now

FALSE

Global Depression

All Smiles

TRUE

Global Depression – BUT no catastrophe

Mega-Catastrophe

Someone then pointed out a gaping hole in Craven’s argument. This grid could be applied to anything that could potentially happen, no matter how unlikely. He uses the example of an invasion of giant mutant space hamsters. The outcome of everyone on the planet being eaten by such creatures is far worse than the costs of building the necessary defence shield to repel them. We must therefore look at the credibility of those who hold the hypothesis against those who do not. If the backers of the hypothesis are the vast majority of leading scientific organisations, and the opponents are few and far between, then we can give much greater weight to the global warming hypothesis. So the grid becomes like this:-

Craven’s Weighted Grid

Action

Global Warming

Lots Now

Little or None Now

FALSE

Global Depression

All Smiles

TRUE

Global Depression – BUT no catastrophe

Mega-Catastrophe

Craven’s Grid with numbers

Craven’s argument becomes much clearer if we put in some numbers. Let us say that the cost of action is 20, but the impact of the catastrophic warming is 400, or 20 times worse. The basic grid becomes:-

The basic grid, with numbers

Action

Global Warming?

Lots Now

Little or None Now

FALSE

-20

0

TRUE

-20

-400

AVERAGE RETURN

-20

-200

The figures are all negative, as the planet is worse off if catastrophic warming occurs, and the people on this planet are worse off if action is taken. The figure of twenty times worse is the upper limit of cost-benefits from the Stern Review (Tol & Yohe 2006). I chose 20 as a base to save on too many decimals when the grid becomes more sophisticated. (Twenty times of benefits over costs is the upper limit of the Stern Review?) Note that there is now an average return, with equal weighting given to whether the hypothesis is true or false. We end up with an expected cost of not taking action of 10 times greater than if we did. We can now incorporate Craven’s argument is that we should give much greater weighting to the consensus scientists than to the sceptics. Let us say the chances of the hypothesis being true are 4 times that of it being false. The weighted grid becomes:-

The weighted grid, with numbers

Action

Global Warming?

%

Lots Now

Little or None Now

FALSE

20%

-20

0

TRUE

80%

-20

-400

RETURN

 

-20

-320

So the expected outcome of not taking action is 16 times worse than of not taking action.

Major issues with Craven’s Grid

There are a number of issues with this basic decision-making grid. Most fundamentally, it relies on opinions of opinions. That is of the expert climate scientists convincing the scientists from other fields that they have a convincing case, then getting this much larger group to pass a resolution. If the vast majority of the membership can be shown to have studied this and agreed that the climate science is as strong as in their disparate fields and used for a basis of voting, then this might be a reliable, secondary, source. However, if there is evidence that the resolution is promulgated by a small number of the membership (and the majority not interested enough to oppose); or that there has been outside pressure to pass a resolution; or that there have been efforts to silence critics through abuse; or that pressure groups try to undermine the research grants on which critical scientists depend – then the resolutions should be at a minimum be viewed as worthless. This is along similar as the verdict of a jury in a court of law is viewed as worthless if there is any evidence jury tampering. Most courts would not just nullify the evidence, they may throw out the case, then prosecute those who would try to pervert the course of justice. If there is considerable evidence of this undue influence, then the balance of opinion should swing the other way. If the argument relies on secondary or tertiary opinions, then one should look very carefully at the actual scientific and policy arguments. As Craven does not offer up this argument (just mentions a paper by Richard Lindzen, to then neglect this issue entirely), I shall leave this as argument as just invalid and ignore it entirely. The alternative – to take as circumstantial evidence that the underlying case is weak – would cloud the analysis. Instead I shall concentrate on the science and policy issues. These can be divided into four areas:-

  1. The climate models do not just predict huge rises in temperatures. Rather, they offer up a range of scenarios. The UNIPCC’s scenarios show a greater than 90% chance of temperatures rising between 1.1oC and 6.4oC this century (UNIPCC 2007.1 p8). Both extremes are fairly unlikely. However, if these scenarios were taken to their peak then the distribution of final temperatures would be skewed towards the top end. That is the cut-off of 2099 is likely to be a matter of timing
  2. The consequence of such temperature rise, the models predict, will not simply be higher temperatures, but severe disruption to weather systems. Extreme weather events, like hurricanes, floods and droughts will become far more frequent. Although impossible to predict the extent of climate disruption with each rise degree in temperature, the impacts are more likely to be more towards the exponential than the linear.
  3. Craven appears to assume that the policy proposed will be entirely successful in combating warming. The UNIPCC recognise that this is not realistic. They propose of target of limiting CO2 to 550ppm (twice the pre-industrial levels) warming to 2.0oC. If this policy successfully contains the warming to 2.0oC, then there would still be some adverse consequences to that warming. Further, this proposal must be signed up to by all the nations of the world and then translated into actual policies.
  4. There are also two broad approaches to policy that need to be considered. The most frequently advocated is mitigation – stopping global warming by stopping the rise in anthropogenic greenhouse emissions, or even reducing them. The other is adaptation – adapting to the climatic changes that occur, such as improving coastal defences; changing crop production; improving irrigation systems; and changing house design.
  5. The policy targets then need to be implemented, recognising that often large, and ill-defined government projects poorly managed, tend to over-run on costs and under-perform on benefits. Further, governments may sometimes get freeloaders, who generate costs but do not contribute anything towards the desired outcome.

This gives four areas that can be analysed separately, under the acronym FCPO.

Forecast – How much temperatures are predicted to rise and in what time period.

Consequences – The forecast change in the weather patterns (droughts, floods, hurricanes, etc.), along with the impacts on crop yields, forestation, sea levels etc.

Policy – The adopted remedy recommended to combat the consequences, along with actual legislation enacted and structures created.

Outturn (of the policy) – The actual policies enacted, along the results of those actions – both intended and unintended.

There is a clear dividing line between the climate science (Forecast and Consequences) and the social sciences (Policy and Outturn). The sub-divisions between the Forecast and Consequences and between Policy and Outturn maybe less distinct, but, as later analysis will demonstrate, are useful for purposes of clarity.

Extending the Grid for FCPO

The grid can now be extended include the four elements discussed in a series of stages. We start with Craven’s scenario were a mitigation policy is 100% successful in combating the adverse effects of global warming.

  1. The costs of action

Extending Craven’s Grid by:-

  • Keeping the costs of mitigation to 20.
  • Extending the True / False Scenario to five categories of warming. (None, lower, median, higher & extreme).
  • Including an extra option of “Adapt”. This is split into two parts. First are low cost contingency plans, given a value of 5. Then there are the reactive costs. These costs rise steeply with more extreme climate change.

This gives a revised grid below.

Costs of Action

Category

Extent

Mitigate

Adapt

None

A

None

-20

-5

0

B

Lower

-20

-10

0

C

Median

-20

-15

0

D

Higher

-20

-25

0

E

Extreme

-20

-45

0

RETURN

-20

-20

0

  1. The Climate Change Impact

This shows the impact of taking action. Points to note

  • The extreme case of not taking action is still twenty times the impact of not taking action.
  • Adapting to climate change is only half as effective as mitigation.
  • The likely catastrophic impacts are likely to be non-linear. I have assumed that it will double with each category rise.

    Climate Change Impact

    Category

    Extent

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    0

    0

    0

    B

    Lower

    0

    -25

    -50

    C

    Median

    0

    -50

    -100

    D

    Higher

    0

    -100

    -200

    E

    Extreme

    0

    -200

    -400

    RETURN

    0

    -75

    -150

  1. Net Costs of Action

    Adding 1. and 2. together.

    Net Costs of taking Action

    Category

    Extent

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    -20

    -5

    0

    B

    Lower

    -20

    -35

    -50

    C

    Median

    -20

    -65

    -100

    D

    Higher

    -20

    -125

    -200

    E

    Extreme

    -20

    -245

    -400

    RETURN

    -20

    -95

    -150

     

  2. Weighted Returns – UNIPCC Scenarios as a basis

    The UNIPCC gives a 90% chance of temperatures rising between 1.1oC and 6.4oC this century. Using this pattern, I assume that the most extreme cases have a 5% probability and the median case as the most likely with a 50% probability. This gives a 20% probability to the lower and higher cases.

    Weighted Net Costs of Action

    Cat

    Extent

    %

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    5%

    -20

    -5

    0

    B

    Lower

    20%

    -20

    -35

    -50

    C

    Median

    50%

    -20

    -65

    -100

    D

    Higher

    20%

    -20

    -125

    -200

    E

    Extreme

    5%

    -20

    -245

    -400

    RETURN

     

    -20.0

    -77.0

    -120.0

     

  3. Weighted Returns – Based on Peak Scenario Warming

    As noted above, the final peak temperatures from the models are likely to be more skewed towards the upper end, as some of the peaks are likely to be well after 2010.

     

     

    Weighted Net Costs of Action

    Cat

    Extent

    %

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    5%

    -20.0

    -5.0

    0.0

    B

    Lower

    5%

    -20.0

    -35.0

    -50.0

    C

    Median

    40%

    -20.0

    -65.0

    -100.0

    D

    Higher

    40%

    -20.0

    -125.0

    -200.0

    E

    Extreme

    10%

    -20.0

    -245.0

    -400.0

    RETURN

     

    -20.0

    -102.5

    -162.5

  4. Weighted returns – restricting CO2 to 550ppm

    The policy to mitigate climate change does not have the unrealistic aim of stopping any future warming. Rather it seeks to stabalise CO2 at 550ppm or double pre-industrial levels. This will equate to a temperature rise of around 2 oC. This is around the lower level impacts.

    The climate change impact grid becomes

    Climate Change Impact

    Category

    Extent

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    0

    0

    0

    B

    Lower

    -20

    -25

    -50

    C

    Median

    -20

    -50

    -100

    D

    Higher

    -20

    -100

    -200

    E

    Extreme

    -20

    -200

    -400

    RETURN

    -16

    -75

    -150

    Note that the lower levels have some benefit from the climate change. But mitigation prevents the most catastrophic scenarios.

    The final grid becomes

    Weighted Net Costs of Action

    Cat

    Extent

    %

    Mitigate

    Adapt

    None

    A

    None

    5%

    -20.0

    -5.0

    0.0

    B

    Lower

    5%

    -40.0

    -35.0

    -50.0

    C

    Median

    40%

    -40.0

    -65.0

    -100.0

    D

    Higher

    40%

    -40.0

    -125.0

    -200.0

    E

    Extreme

    10%

    -40.0

    -245.0

    -400.0

    RETURN

     

    -39.0

    -102.5

    -162.5

     

The FCPO Grid

The grid derived simply, but effectively summarises the “Consensus” case.

  1. There is a high degree of likelihood that we will have some serious global warming with huge consequences for the planet and the human race.
  2. The best policy is to limit CO2 to double pre-industrial levels. Re-active adaptation strategies are risky and ineffective compared with mitigation.
  3. The expected average costs of doing nothing are far greater than any costs of mitigation.
  4. More importantly than any expected average impact, there is a very real possibility of a massive catastrophe.

What is more it is a way of effectively gauging some of the arguments, underpinned with some risk analysis. By trying to turn the uncertainties into our best-guess risks we can get a more balanced and rigorous assessment of the science than Greg Craven’s. Further, we can also bring into the same analysis the potential effectiveness of any policy, and the project management aspect of delivering the planned results.

However, the ability of this grid to evaluate the science is limited. It can only be used for most top-down or broad-brush aspects. It is a way to get the relative importance of various aspects of science and policy within the totality of the subject, when they are vastly different in degree. If used for splitting hairs, then this will just be another tool to advance the “shouting match”. To focus and clarify the evaluation, a new question is required. “What is the worst that can happen?” is too loaded towards thinking of extreme, but highly improbable, events.

The New Question

To focus and clarify the evaluation, a new question is required. “What is the worst that can happen?” is too loaded towards thinking of extreme, but highly improbable, events. The FCPO Grid looks at both the future scenarios projected by the science and at our collective ability to provide a remedy. There the new question becomes

By taking action, is there, on the balance of the evidence, an expectation that the future state will be improved?

The climate change consensus would contend that this is clear-cut – something that my FCPO grid replicates.

 

References

Craven, Greg 2007 Jun – Youtube video “The Most Terrifying Video You’ll Ever See

Craven, Greg 2007 Oct – Youtube video “How it all ends

Craven, Greg 2009 – What’s the Worst That Could Happen?

Craven, Greg Website – http://www.gregcraven.org/

Tol & Yohe 2006 – A Review of the Stern Review – WORLD ECONOMICS • Vol. 7 • No. 4 • October–December 2006

UNIPCC 2007.1 – Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report – Summary for Policymakers (Dec 08 format)

The Division of Labour & Climate Science Part 1

Bishop Hill displays to an excellent short video at TED by Matt Ridley, encapsulating the concepts of the division of labour and comparative advantage. One thing that Matt Ridley leaves out is the creative destructiveness of competition through supplanting the existing order. Specialisation leads to new products and processes. By implication, the established processes and products are overturned. (Joseph Schumpeter needs to be added to the list of Adam Smith and David Ricardo)

It is not just in the sphere of production that these concepts apply. It is also with empirical science, be it economics, medical research or climatology. With complex data and many facets to the subject, there is scope for division of labour into

–         Data collectors,

–         Data analysts & measurers,

–         Statisticians to validate the analysis,

–         Theoreticians to innovate or create new ideas.

–         Mathematicians, to provide tools for analysis.

–         Methodologists, to provide structures of meaning and assess the boundaries of science.

–         This is alongside the general sub-divisions of the subject, which may change over time.

–         Alongside greater specialists there is also scope for generalist assessors who get a total perspective of the corpus of knowledge, weighing up the status of competing ideas.

–         Academic competition (to gain status) leads to improvements, but can also lead to diversity in conclusions. It also tends to blunt the conclusions where data is ambiguous or fuzzy.

This makes things a bit messy. In economics there has ceased to be any dominant schools of thought or policy prescriptions. But in climatology we are lucky to have the IPCC, which divides the world into a small group of generalist experts (who agree their main conclusions) and the masses, who accept the wisdom handed down. A bit like the guild system, that kept England in the Dark Ages.